(Editor's note: Below is the written testimony of Michael D. LaFaive, director of the Morey Fiscal Policy Initiative at the Mackinac Center, submitted today to the State Senate Finance Committee.)
Executive Summary: A recent Michigan State University report on the Michigan film subsidy program is of limited use in determining the program's success because it failed to enter the film subsidy's costs into the economic model used to calculate the benefits to Michigan's economy. This is analogous to an accountant leaving the liabilities off a company's balance sheet and concluding it has a high net worth.
The omission is especially troubling given that a substantial portion of the subsidy costs are actual cash outlays — checks to film producers from the Michigan Treasury. When a "multiplier effect" is applied to the tax revenues taken from the private economy to pay the subsidies — balancing the "multiplier" the MSU study authors applied to the supposed benefits — the costs of the program would be seen to be even higher. At the very least, the state should commission a new report based on the very same expenditure data used in the MSU study, but mandate that the costs of the program be included in the model. It should also require the study be peer-reviewed by professional economists and commissioned by a neutral state agency, such as the state office of the auditor general. |
Thank you for this opportunity to submit my testimony in writing. I regret that an earlier engagement prevents me from attending this hearing in person. I would have loved to have had a "cameo" at a hearing about films in Michigan.
In early 2008, state lawmakers passed an incentive program for filmmakers that provides refundable tax credits (potential cash subsidies) to those who produce films in the Great Lake State. The program has been a public relations boon for its advocates. The glare of Hollywood lights and the excitement of "new jobs" seem to have convinced many people the program is a success. They should look more carefully.
For a variety of reasons, government subsidies targeted at particular industries have a terrible track record when it comes to boosting a state's economy. This conclusion is supported by economic theory, history and empirical research. Hollywood magic cannot replace economic fundamentals.
The MSU Study Fails to Include Costs, Producing a Flawed Methodology
The Michigan Economic Development Corp., which oversees the Michigan Film Office, commissioned Michigan State University's Center for Economic Analysis to provide a study of the economic impact of the spending done by films receiving refundable tax credits under the Michigan Film Incentive program. The resulting report, written by Steven Miller and Abdul Abdulkadri, was published on Feb. 6, 2009.
The MSU report has two strengths. To the authors' credit, they take care to exclude from their calculations film spending that probably had no impact on Michigan's economy because it likely occurred outside the state. This decision is noteworthy, not simply because it was the right thing to do, but also because the Michigan Film Office does not appear to have shown similar care in its own report on the MFI program. Hence, the MSU study's authors conclude that $65.4 million was spent in Michigan by the 32 films for which they had data, while the Film Office states that total Michigan expenditures were $125 million for the 35 films for which it had data (the Film Office, writing later, had information for several additional films).
The MSU figure appears to be the better estimate, although it is difficult to say with perfect certainty, since the original data has not been made publicly available. Nevertheless, to argue (as the MEDC did to the Mackinac Center's Kathy Hoekstra) that the difference between the two figures is due to the MSU researchers using earlier, unaudited figures, is implausible. Those early figures would have had to be inexcusably inaccurate to produce an estimate that was off by nearly 50 percent. Nor is it likely that the three extra films the Film Office included could account for such a startling difference. The MSU authors' care in this regard has thus helped raise important questions about the Film Office numbers — questions that would have been difficult to ask otherwise, given the lack of public access to the original data.
The second strength of the MSU report lies in a similar area. The Film Office report states that the films' spending produced 2,800 Michigan jobs. The MSU report mentions direct gains of 2,763 jobs, but adds that these involved short-term employment of just 23 days on average, producing a "full-time equivalent" of just 254 jobs. Again, the MSU report disclosed important information that appears to have been omitted in the Film Office report.
Unfortunately, the MSU report is otherwise a flawed product. The authors take great pains to explain the workings of the model they employ — known as REMI[*] Policy Insight — and the impact that film industry expenditures have on Michigan's economy as they are turned over through the "multiplier" effect. This multiplier effect involves subsequent rounds of spending. For example, a film company may contract with a hotelier, caterer and set designer. Those individuals then spend the money hiring new employees or buying more ingredients to make their products and so on.
The authors report that due to such multiplier effects, more jobs were created than just 254 full-time equivalents that were the direct result of the films' hiring. Rather, they concluded, "film productions generated 1,102 year-round equivalent jobs in 2008" and "based on generally accepted economic theory, multiplier impacts will increase over time." They report that with the multiplier effect, state economic output will increase by $335.6 million through 2012.
News agencies around the state dutifully reported this apparent good news — which is probably what the Michigan Film Office had in mind. But these numbers are grossly overstated because the paper's authors deliberately excluded the costs associated with the program.
In other words, significant costs to taxpayers were not entered into the model. Had they been, the output would have been different, perhaps dramatically so — showing far fewer jobs created, for instance, or even a net job loss.
Thus, when MSU's Center for Economic Analysis boasted in a press release that the film incentive law was a "big hit," they did so knowing the model used in their study had been programmed with only the benefits of film expenditures, not the costs. Ignoring these costs in the model is roughly equivalent to a certified public accountant omitting a balance sheet's liabilities and then touting the success of the company.
The costs of the Michigan Film Incentive are significant. In 2008, the program is said to have produced $48 million in refundable tax credits; estimates for future years' costs could exceed $200 million. Due to the extraordinarily generous film credits being "refundable," a substantial portion of these costs represents actual cash outlays - State of Michigan checks written to producers - rather than the "forgone revenues" of most targeted tax breaks. Moreover, these subsidy outlays represent revenue taken from Michigan employers and families. If that money had been left in their hands, it would also have generated a multiplier effect. In other words, if the proponents of the film subsidies attribute a multiplier effect on the benefit side, they must also acknowledge the same effect on the cost side.
MSU Study Contradicts Author's Explanation for Ignoring Costs
On Monday of this week, I asked Steven Miller, co-author of the MSU report, why they had not included the costs of the program in the work. He quickly responded that the costs were left out because he and his co-author were measuring the "economic impact of the film industry expenditures, not necessarily the incentive program."
However, the title of study belies this assertion: "The Economic Impact of Michigan's Motion Picture Production Industry and the Michigan Motion Picture Production Credit" (emphasis added). It is hard to imagine from the title alone why the paper would not examine the net impact of the incentive program — that is, why it would not include the costs, too.
And consider the opening paragraph of the press release that accompanied the report: "A Michigan State University study has found that the state of Michigan's law providing tax credits for film production companies that shoot their movies in Michigan is a big time hit."
At a minimum, the MSU report and press release should have included a disclaimer that the costs of the program were not included, so that news agencies and others would have a better perspective on the report's conclusions.
Ironically, on Page 4 of the study, the authors write, "deriving meaningful estimates of the economic impact of film production expenditures requires careful consideration of what makes up the direct expenditures and proper assignment of these direct expenditures to various industries."
In fact, meaningful estimates of any government program's efficacy require careful consideration of all its aspects — including its costs. Without a massive and costly state subsidy, the authors would have had little filmmaker activity on which to report.
How could MSU publish a study with such a fundamental flaw? The REMI economic model does not force its users to input a budget constraint, and so the model treated all of the expenditure data the MSU authors entered as the equivalent of a free lunch.
It is not. In order to enrich filmmakers through taxpayer subsidies, the state must necessarily diminish the wealth of others.
Assume for a moment that the program really did create 1,102 jobs in 2008. At a cost of $48 million, this works out to a state subsidy of $43,557 per job; a staggering sum in light of Michigan's fiscal problems.
More troubling yet is that this program was born on the heels of 2007's $600 million Michigan business tax surcharge, up to one-third of which may one day be eaten up each year by checks written to filmmakers. Lawmakers should realize that Michigan businesses might easily have created a mere 1,100 additional jobs in 2008 if the Legislature had simply not raised their taxes.
Economic Literature Documents, Chides Misuse of Models
The MSU authors should have recognized that excluding the costs of the film incentive program leads to significant distortions. Economics 101 - not to mention common sense - teaches each student that everything has a cost, even if it is just an opportunity cost. This is one of the most fundamental precepts of economic science.
The MSU authors may argue that leaving out the costs somehow does not invalidate their conclusions, but to do so, they would have to rebut an extensive body of economic literature that documents the misapplication of economic models.
For example, in his 1993 paper "The Misuse of Regional Economic Models," economist Edwin Mills showed how models like REMI are misapplied to advance policy goals. He offered up a number of conjectures for a model's misuse, several of which included:
Second, to justify increased spending, government officials must identify some publicly desired goal to be accomplished by government spending. Creation of new jobs is among the best such goals that can be found. Third, they must make it plausible that government can accomplish the goal in a way that the private sector cannot. This is where REMI is so valuable. It is a complex computer model that lay people cannot understand or evaluate, and it has important scientific merits. Thus, the frequent government claims that the best scientific model available shows that x thousand jobs will be created by the project helps to carry the day.
In a 2005 book about business economics and finance, Lansing-area economist Patrick Anderson made a public plea for ethics in economic impact analysis, arguing that "because the claimed economic impact of a proposed development can affect political support for a proposed project — and sometimes taxpayer funding — an incentive often exists to exaggerate the benefits." Whether intentional or not, a simple way to exaggerate benefits in an impact analysis is to exclude the costs.
Lastly, in his 2006 academic paper "Economic Impact Studies: Instruments for Political Shenanigans?" John L. Compton argues that, "Most economic impact studies are commissioned to legitimize a political position rather than to search for economic truth. Often the result is mischievous procedures that produce large numbers that study sponsors seek to support a predetermined position."
Compton goes on to specifically criticize ignoring total costs, omitting opportunity costs and abusing multipliers. The study, published in the Journal of Travel Research, focuses primarily on tourism-related impact analysis. Many of its arguments against impact analysis, however, apply to analysis of other economic development programs.
In fact, Compton's critique of tourism analyses is directly relevant to the MSU paper, which, among other things, cites film-related tourism as a benefit of the subsidies. Members of Michigan's tourism industry have seized upon this to trumpet the film incentive program's alleged virtues.
Why Government Subsidies Won't Save Michigan's Economy
There are many explanations for why government has a difficult time creating net new jobs with targeted subsidies like the Michigan Film Incentive. First, government must tax Peter to pay Paul. That creates an inherent risk of creating no new jobs, but rather just shifting them around.
Second, redistributing tax revenues costs money. The officials who run these programs don't work for free. For example, Michigan Film Office Director Janet Lockwood alone makes more than $95,000 annually plus benefits, and members of the MEDC who work with the film program are well-compensated, too. One published report indicates that the Michigan Film Office also received $2 million for "marketing efforts." This is money taken first from Michigan employers who might otherwise use it to create jobs.
Third, Lansing civil servants and political appointees are unlikely to possess special talents when it comes to picking winners and losers in the marketplace. Even Wall Street experts have a checkered record when it comes to outguessing the market as a whole. There is no reason for taxpayers to think that political appointees who have no money of their own at risk will do better than Wall Street.
Lastly, bureaucrats may be inclined to make political decisions, rather than economic ones. This political incentive will tend to lower the return on a public "investment" made with our tax dollars.
Hard empirical evidence suggests that these and other factors hobble government "economic development" programs of every sort. In their 2004 literature review of economic development programs, University of Iowa economists Alan Peters and Peter Fisher noted that states spend about $48 billion to $50 billion annually on state and local incentive programs with little to show for it. Their article, "The Failure of Economic Development Programs," concludes in part:
The upshot of all of this is that on this most basic question of all — whether incentives induce significant new investment or jobs — we simply do not know the answer. Since these programs probably cost state and local governments about $40-$50 billion a year, one would expect some clear and undisputed evidence of their success. This is not the case. In fact, there are very good reasons — theoretical, empirical, and practical — to believe that economic development incentives have little or no impact on firm location and investment decisions.
And
We need to begin by lowering (policymakers') expectations about their ability to micromanage economic growth and making the case for a more sensible view of the role of government — providing the foundations for growth through sound fiscal practices, quality public infrastructure, and good education systems — and then letting the economy take care of itself.
Recommendation: Increase Film Program Transparency, and Redo the Film Subsidy Study Using Valid Methodology
As you can see, there are good reasons to believe that the Michigan Film Incentive, like other targeted economic development programs, is not capable of generating net new jobs or economic growth. This calls the wisdom of program into doubt.
Nevertheless, if policymakers are intent on continuing state subsidies to the film industry, the state should consider consulting with the company that actually created the REMI Policy Insight model — the model used by MSU economists — to replicate the work produced for the MEDC, but with one important change: The costs of the program would be included.
The "direct expenditure assumptions" data used by the MSU Center for Economic Analysis is available to the public and could be easily provided to REMI's economists in Amherst, Mass. The total cost of the program could also be provided (including the net MBT subsidy), but for the best results, it might be ideal if the state provided REMI economists with a breakdown of subsidies per project and the estimated costs by year. The question is, would the Michigan Film Office cooperate?
To date, the Michigan Film Office has been decidedly stingy when it comes to providing detailed information about this expenditure of taxpayer dollars — so much so that Mackinac Center scholars have argued that the Film Office violated the law by failing to provide the type of detailed information demanded of the program by statute. In March, the Center pointed out that the Michigan Film Office issued a report that was "sorely lacking in key information required by state law." Patrick J. Wright, senior legal analyst for the Mackinac Center, explained that state law mandates detailed spending figures for each film receiving the incentive program's refundable tax credits, but the Michigan Film Office supplied just total spending figures.
Here's the bottom line: Because it ignored the program's costs, the report produced by the Center for Economic Analysis at Michigan State University is of little use in determining the success or failure of the state's film incentive program. Unfortunately, the report, issued under the imprimatur of Michigan State University, was seized upon and widely reported by the media.
The state should commission a new report based on the very same expenditure data used in the existing one, but mandate that the costs of the program be included in the model. The cost of paying for a second analysis should be funded from the existing Michigan Film Office budget, but commissioned by a neutral state agency, such as the state office of the auditor general. The paper should also be subject to publicly acknowledged peer-review prior to publication. Moreover, I would recommend that the state refrain from approving any more film incentive awards until the new study is complete.
Thank you for your time, senators. Please feel free to contact me with any questions.
#####
Michael D. LaFaive is director of the Morey Fiscal Policy Initiative at the Mackinac Center for Public Policy, a research and educational institute headquartered in Midland, Mich. Permission to reprint in whole or in part is hereby granted, provided that the author and the Center are properly cited.
[*] REMI is an acronym for Regional Economic Models Inc.
The Mackinac Center for Public Policy is a nonprofit research and educational institute that advances the principles of free markets and limited government. Through our research and education programs, we challenge government overreach and advocate for a free-market approach to public policy that frees people to realize their potential and dreams.
Please consider contributing to our work to advance a freer and more prosperous state.