A guide to understanding telecommunications law and regulation in Michigan and the United States.
Telecommunications technology has undergone tremendous leaps of progress throughout the past century. Samuel Morse first telegraphed a four-word message over a copper wire in 1844. Today, billions of people worldwide converse daily on wireless phones that double as cameras, and they access a library’s worth of data in seconds from home or office via broadband connections.
The social and economic value of this continuous information flow cannot be overestimated. Knowledge is indeed power when applied by commercial firms to precisely gauge real-time market conditions across the globe, or by citizens downloading news and information from diverse sources to improve their lives. Indeed, annual U.S. telecommunications revenues have exceeded $300 billion in recent years, a testament to the demand for voice, data and video transmissions.[1]
This reliance on telecommunications necessitates public policies that promote innovation and ensure network reliability and security. But for all the mind-boggling technicalities of “frequency division multiplexing” and “asynchronous transference,” telecommunications policy need not be complex if guided by time-tested economic principles.
These principles form the basis of the policy recommendations included in this primer. We begin with a plain-language description of common technologies and a condensed history of the industry. These sections are followed by a status report on the telecommunications market and summaries of controlling statutes and regulations. A glossary is also provided, along with links to relevant Web sites.
A greater understanding of telecommunications among lawmakers, the media and the public is sorely needed. Despite the direct impact on the nation, telecommunications policies have largely been crafted by unseen hands in ineffective ways. Consequently, America now trails a number of Asian and European nations in deployment of the most advanced wireless and broadband technologies.[2]
Michigan is a key state in the reform calculus by virtue of its reliance on technology and its sheer economic muscle. The number of high-speed lines statewide increased tenfold in the past four years, from 81,223 in 1999 to 848,837 today — the 11th largest number in the nation.[3] Moreover, the market share of competing service providers in Michigan is exceeded only by New York and Rhode Island.[4]
Yet the degree of penetration of broadband and other advanced telecom applications in even top-ranking states like Michigan still lags that of global frontrunners in Europe, as well as that of many Asian countries, such as Korea, Hong Kong and Singapore. Absent reform, existing telecom policies that inhibit investment and innovation will continue to undermine job creation and economic growth, while inducing businesses to locate abroad.
The regulatory process always trails the pace of technological change. In the case of telecommunications, the regulatory regime of price controls, service mandates and marketing restrictions imposed decades ago has been overtaken by the abundant, affordable telecom options available today. No longer are consumers at the mercy of the government-sanctioned “Ma Bell” monopoly. Competition among various technologies and providers has rendered rate regulation and service boundaries wholly obsolete.
There is, therefore, considerable opportunity to improve telecommunications policies at both the state and federal levels.
At the federal level, the regulations governing competition in local calling over the traditional wireline network were recently overturned as arbitrary and overreaching by the U.S. Circuit Court of Appeals in Washington, D.C. This marked the third time in eight years that these federal rules were judged improper. Subsequently, both the Federal Communications Commission (FCC) and the Bush administration decided — wisely — against an appeal, thereby opening the way for much-needed reforms.
At the state level, Michigan’s Telecommunications Act is slated to sunset on Dec. 31, 2005. In devising a statutory update, legislators have the opportunity to abolish antiquated regulations that have inhibited innovation and undermined telecommunications investment and job creation in the state.
Transforming telecom policies will demand aggressive oversight of regulators by lawmakers, the media and the general public. Resistance to reform will run strong among those with a vested interest in the status quo. But enhancing consumer benefits and technological innovation matters far more than preserving regulators’ powers or special-interest advantages.
Recent events have illuminated the path to progress. Shortly after the FCC’s rules on competition in local calling were overturned, executives of the “Baby Bells” called upon their rivals to negotiate commercial agreements for network access without government interference. Within days, SBC Telecommunications Inc. and Sage Telecom Inc. struck an agreement, while Verizon and BellSouth have also announced agreements with wholesale customers both large and small.
The message is unmistakable: “This is proof positive that free markets can work in telecommunications as they do throughout the U.S. economy,” said Walter B. McCormick Jr., president and CEO of the United States Telecom Association. “This is real-world evidence that we do not need to spend months and years in court defending the past and putting future telecom investment and job creation on hold. All it takes to move forward constructively for the country is reasonable people sitting down in good faith at the negotiating table.”[5]
Plain Old Telephone Service
Plain Old Telephone Service (POTS) refers to the basic voice service traditionally transmitted over the copper wire network. The sound waves of a caller’s voice are converted by the telephone handset into electrical signals that travel over the network. The copper network is prone to interference, and the signal may weaken over distance, thus requiring amplification along the way. See Chart 1.
The copper network originally carried only “analog” signals, which travel in a continuous stream and require a dedicated circuit. But the network has been upgraded also to carry “digital” signals, which do not require a continuously open and dedicated circuit, thereby increasing network transmission capacity.
Telephone Numbers
Telephone numbers in the United States are organized according to the North American Numbering Plan. The numbering plan is administered by a private firm selected by the Federal Communications Commission through competitive bidding. The numbering plan is subject to directives from regulatory authorities in member countries.
The 10-digit numbers used in the United States consist of three separate codes that designate the route and billing of every call. Each number, when dialed or pressed, emits a tone deciphered by network computers. The first three digits, known as the area code (or Numbering Plan Area), identify a metropolitan area. The next three digits, known as the exchange (or Prefix), specify the central office from which the call is routed to a local destination. The last four digits (Station) represent the individual customer line.
Under federal law, a customer must be allowed to keep a telephone number when changing service providers within a local area. This “number portability” requires a master database to determine whether the customer line is maintained by the original service provider or assigned to a competitor.
Circuit-based Technology
Circuit-based technology, commonly referred to as “analog,” relies on a dedicated, continuous transmission path through the network. A dedicated circuit is among the most reliable technologies, although it is not the most efficient in terms of network capacity.
Packet-based Technology
Packet-based technology, commonly referred to as “digital,” does not require a dedicated path through the network, but instead arranges data in fragmented “packets” to speed transmission. Each packet is routed using the best network connection available at a given time, and the packets are reassembled in their original order at the destination of the call.
DSL
Digital Subscriber Line (DSL) technology enables data to be transmitted at high speeds through the copper-wire telephone network. A “transceiver” linked to a personal computer connects to the network of an Internet Service Provider through the local telephone network. Data is compressed into digital packets and routed by the Internet Service Provider to the World Wide Web.
ISDN
The Integrated Services Digital Network technology (ISDN) allows a single copper-wire telephone line to transmit both voice and data signals. Users must dial in to establish a network connection, and fees are typically assessed based on the duration of transmission. ISDN is only available within 3.4 miles of a service provider’s central office.
T1 (or DS1)
A T1 line is a high-speed digital circuit that provides the equivalent of 24 voice-grade lines (or channels) of transmission capacity. The line is leased as a direct connection to a computer system, an Internet Service Provider or a destination specified by the customer. A T1 line is capable of transmitting large text files, as well as graphics and audio.
T3 (or DS3)
A T3 line is a higher-speed digital circuit that provides the equivalent of 672 voice-grade lines (or channels) of transmission capacity. The T3 line serves as the principal artery for heavy volumes of Internet traffic, including transmissions generated by corporations, universities and Internet Service Providers. The T3 is capable of full-screen, full-motion video transmissions.
Fiber to the Home
Fiber to the Home (FTTH), also known as Fiber to the Premises (FTTP), entails replacing copper telephone lines with optical fiber cable at the user’s residence to increase transmission capacity. The hair-thin strands of glass fiber carry pulses of light that deliver volumes more data at higher speeds. Transmitters are needed to convert electrical impulses from a computer into light streams.
OCn
OCn, or Optical Carrier Networks, transmit large amounts of data as light signals. The networks vary in capacity. An OC1, for example, can carry the equivalent of a T3 line. Telephone companies use OC12 systems between central offices to carry some 8,000 simultaneous conversations on a single strand of fiber.
Coaxial Cable
The coaxial cable through which television programming is delivered can also accommodate voice and high-speed data transmissions. Coaxial cable requires use of a modem to properly relay signals to the Internet and other network connections. Modem signals are first received by a neighborhood “node” that directs hundreds of such transmissions to network connections at the cable vendor’s facility. Amplifiers boost signal strength along the transmission route.
VOIP
Voice Over Internet Protocol (VOIP) sometimes refers to private networks that use packet-based technology to transmit calls. The sound waves of a caller’s voice are digitally encoded and transmitted as packets of data. The message is decoded to voice at the destination of the call. Private networks allow users to prioritize call routing to ensure transmission speed and quality.
VOIP also refers to calls transmitted over the public Internet in order to bypass the local calling network. Unlike private networks, calls routed over the public Internet may be impacted by network congestion associated with multiple users transmitting large amounts of data simultaneously. However, these technical challenges are expected to be overcome as the technology continues to advance.
Cellular Service
Cellular telephones essentially operate as two-way radios that are also capable of transmitting video and text data. Calls are transmitted as electrical signals within the radio-wave channels allocated to service providers. The signals are relayed between cellular towers that connect with switches to other networks, including the wireline network. Calls may be transmitted as analog or digital signals. See Chart 2 above.
Wireless Local Loop
Wireless Local Loops use rooftop antennas rather than copper wire or optical fiber to transmit telephone calls. Unlike cellular calling, wireless local loops only provide service between fixed points. The antennas relay the signals to “hub” receivers, which interconnect with the wire line network.
Spectrum
“Electromagnetic spectrum” is the scientific term for the full range of electric, magnetic and visible radiation in the universe. Waves within the spectrum vary in size, frequency and energy, and they are classified by their wavelength. The waves can extend from one-billionth of a meter, as in gamma rays, to centimeters and meters, as in radio waves. Waves of similar length are categorized into bands. Within bands, waves travel at various frequencies. The Federal Communications Commission allocates licenses for use of specific radio-wave frequencies. Click on "More Images..." above to see Chart 3.
Spectrum capacity continues to expand as technology improves at delineating new frequencies and reducing interference.
WiFi
Wireless Fidelity, commonly referred to as “WiFi,” is a local computer or audio network that uses high-frequency radio signals to transmit and receive data over short distances.
Satellite
Satellites operate as celestial antennas, relaying signals to and from computers to various Internet Service Providers. The transmissions are weather-sensitive and more prone to landscape interference than other technologies.
Broadband Over Power line (BPL)
A number of utilities are experimenting with using power lines to transmit voice and data signals. The existing wiring of homes and businesses presents opportunities for a variety of applications. Computer adapters are necessary to filter the various signals.
Alexander Graham Bell patented the telephone on March 7, 1876, just hours ahead of rival inventor Elisha Gray. Bell’s initial experiments were an attempt to enable a telegraph wire to carry simultaneous messages. His backers were intent on developing new technology to challenge the Western Union telegraph monopoly.
Bell succeeded beyond his expectations. On March 10, 1876, he placed what now ranks among the most important telephone calls in history. To his young assistant in an adjacent room he said, “Mr. Watson, come here. I want to see you.”
Telephone technology took another leap in 1891, when Almon Strowger, a Kansas City undertaker who was fed up with nosy operators, patented a “switch” that could automatically relay calls to their destination without operator assistance.
Daily telephone use in the United States grew from four calls per 1,000 people to 37 calls per 1,000 people between 1876 and 1894.[6] But once the Bell patents expired, thousands of competitors began wiring the nation, increasing the daily calling average per 1,000 people from 37 in 1895 to 391 in 1910. By 1907, Bell rivals controlled 51 percent of local telephone service.[7]
Michigan’s first local telephone company, Ontonagon Telephone Co., emerged in 1877, when an Upper Peninsula businessman strung a line between his inland office and the Lake Superior port at Ontonagon.[8] By the century’s turn, some 200 telephone companies were providing service in the state.
The surge of competition in the early 1900s prompted a takeover spree of rivals by American Telephone and Telegraph (AT&T). But AT&T’s acquisitions troubled federal authorities, who began mulling antitrust action. This prompted AT&T officials to propose what subsequently became known as the “Kingsbury Commitment.” On Dec. 19, 1913, AT&T agreed to sell $30 million of its Western Union stock and to allow competitors to interconnect with its network. The company also pledged that for every new local system it acquired, it would sell an equal share of lines.
The Kingsbury Commitment was wholly in keeping with the brilliant strategy of AT&T’s President Theodore Newton Vail. The regulatory emphasis on interconnection cemented AT&T’s control of the telephone network. And, the constraints on line acquisition did not keep the company from concentrating its hold in major markets. Thus, Vail was well-positioned to promote telephone service as a “natural monopoly.” Public officials, eager to regulate the nascent industry, embraced Vail’s motto of “One Policy, One System, Universal Service.”
As the nation’s dominant service provider, AT&T had the most to gain from government-erected barriers to market entry. The more difficult it was to launch competitive service, the more secure was AT&T’s market share.
Then, as now, the absence of government interference would likely have spurred technological innovations that would have prevented any one company from achieving market dominance.
Congress first vested federal regulatory authority over telephone services in the Interstate Commerce Commission, under the Mann-Elkins Act of 1910. This legislation adopted the practice of local franchising already begun by states and municipalities to control rates and service quality.
Michigan first regulated telephone service in 1913, when the Legislature directed the Michigan Public Service Commission to oversee the burgeoning industry.[9]
The theory of “natural monopoly,” now widely questioned, presumed that redundant telephone infrastructure was economically inefficient. For example, a 1921 report by the Michigan Public Service Commission concluded that “competition resulted in duplication of investment,” and that states were justified in denying requests by rivals to deploy new lines.[10] A report that same year from the U.S. House of Representatives likewise concluded that “there is nothing to be gained by local competition in the telephone business.”[11]
The same view was also misapplied to electric power supply and water treatment, triggering creation of a massive regulatory structure to temper government-sanctioned monopoly power. In hindsight, competition could have restrained utility monopolies by generating new technologies and applications that instead took decades to achieve.
The drawbacks of the regulated-monopoly approach are now more widely recognized. Firms that enjoy government protection from competition, and for whom rates of return are guaranteed through regulation, face less financial pressure to innovate or operate efficiently. Moreover, regulators often become so committed to the regulatory structure that they regard competition as a threat, rather than as a potential solution to the very structural conditions that led to the adoption of regulation.
By 1925, telecom rate regulation was in effect across most of the nation, and competition was either discouraged or explicitly prohibited. The regulatory structure was finalized when Congress created the Federal Communications Commission in 1934.
In enacting the Communications Act of 1934, Congress authorized the new agency to impose service requirements priced at regulated rates. Any deviations in product or service required government approval, a laborious process then as now. Many such regulatory strictures persist despite fierce market competition.
As noted by a 1988 Department of Commerce report: “The chief focus of the Communications Act of 1934 was on the regulation of telecommunications, not necessarily its maximum development and promotion. (T)he drafters of the legislation saw the talents and resources of the industry presenting more of a challenge to the public interest than an opportunity for national progress.”[12]
Thus, with the cooperation of state and federal officials, AT&T secured its dominance over telephone service for decades to come, controlling more than 80 percent of all telephone lines and assuming family status as “Ma Bell.”[13]
Intent on remaining a government-sanctioned monopoly, AT&T had little interest in selling network access to alternative service providers. (In recent years, ironically, AT&T has been the principal advocate of forcing local telephone companies to provide network access to rivals, itself included, at below-cost rates.)
Challenges to AT&T’s protected standing intensified in the 1970s, prompting the FCC to allow limited competition in long-distance services. Local service, however, remained off-limits to competition. This regulatory disconnect between local and long-distance calling continues today, despite technological advances that have rendered obsolete any meaningful distinction between the two.
In 1974, the U.S. Justice Department filed an antitrust lawsuit against AT&T based on complaints by MCI and other long-distance service providers. The lawsuit went unresolved for eight years. But in 1982, the company settled with the government under conditions ordained by Judge Harold H. Greene of the Federal District Court for the District of Columbia.
The landmark settlement required AT&T to divest its local operating companies and limit its services to the long-distance market. Hence, in 1984, Michigan Bell became part of Ameritech, one of seven regional “Baby Bells” that assumed control of local calling services.
AT&T was allowed to continue manufacturing telephone equipment. (These operations were later spun off as Lucent Technologies.) Judge Greene retained jurisdiction over the case for more than a decade, effectively elevating himself to the role of national telecom czar. Virtually every major business decision required approval by both the judge and the FCC.
Thus, the creature of government was dismembered by government, demonstrating yet again that “government has nothing to give anybody except what it first takes from somebody, and a government that’s big enough to give you everything you want is big enough to take away everything you’ve got.”[14]
A subsequent series of mergers and acquisitions reduced the number of regional operating companies from seven to four: SBC, Verizon, BellSouth and Qwest — now commonly referred to as “incumbents.” In Michigan, Ameritech was acquired by SBC in 1999, while Verizon acquired GTE, another Michigan carrier, in 2000.
Competition in long-distance service has yielded dramatic consumer benefits in the form of lower prices and improved service quality. Average revenues per minute for interstate and international calls originating in the United States dropped from 62 cents per minute in 1983 to 10 cents per minute in 2001.[15] In many instances, calling across state lines and even international borders costs less than local toll calls within a single state.
The telecommunications industry, in every respect, has grown vastly over the past two decades. Advances in fiber optics, wireless and other signal-processing technologies have created new markets and made new network infrastructure far more affordable, increasing competition.
In recent years, wireless telephony has presented the greatest competitive challenge to wireline service. Cellular subscriptions have increased from just 92,000 nationwide in 1984 to more than 158 million today.[16] The number of local wire lines, meanwhile, decreased by nearly 2 million between 1999 and 2002.[17]
Competition yields lower rates and promotes higher usage. For example, the number of wireless call minutes increased 61 percent between 2000 and 2002.[18] The biggest market growth is now among lower-income customers, reflecting the increased affordability of service.
A major factor driving the extraordinary growth in wireless services has been the loosening of government’s grip on the broadcast spectrum. In the early 1990s, the FCC had restricted the number of wireless carriers to two per market area. See Chart 5. The 1993 Budget Reconciliation Act, however, forced the FCC to auction spectrum for up to six carriers per market. Consequently, by 2003 more than 95 percent of the nation was served by at least three wireless services.
This growth results from wireless carriers competing in the open market to build their own networks, with none of the regulatory management or subsidization that has characterized wireline competition.
Cable television companies and Internet Service Providers (ISPs) increasingly are adding telephony to their offerings. See Chart 6. Cable telephony now serves 2.5 million residential subscribers, an increase of 70 percent annually since 2001.[19]
Voice Over Internet Protocol, or VOIP, will have experienced a compound annual growth rate of 96.7 percent between 2000 and 2007, according to calculations by the consulting firm of Frost & Sullivan. The firm also forecasts that by 2007, over 60 percent of long-distance traffic will travel over VOIP networks.
High-speed telecommunications services, in particular, have experienced tremendous growth, as illustrated by the chart above. An estimated 83 percent of U.S. homes now have access to cable or DSL broadband,[20] while some 59 percent of Americans access the Internet from home or work — a number projected to increase to 73 percent by 2007.[21]
Advances in technology have allowed voice, video and data services to be combined in new applications. This “convergence” is increasingly available across all types of telecommunications media.
Telecom Act of 1996
The breakup of AT&T in 1984 unleashed products and services unforeseen by regulators or the courts. But the rapid pace of innovation also produced regulatory inconsistencies between various products and service providers, which Congress sought to remedy with passage of the Telecommunications Act of 1996.
Mindful of the benefits realized through long-distance competition, lawmakers declared an end to the monopoly franchise system governing local wireline calling.
The 1996 act set the conditions by which carriers would be allowed to provide local and long-distance services. Among the most significant provisions was the requirement that the Baby Bells and other “incumbent” local carriers provide network access to rivals at regulated rates. These rivals — referred to in the industry as “competitors” — included long-distance, cable and wireless firms. In return for providing access, the Bells were allowed to enter the long-distance market, offer cable services and manufacture equipment once regulators were satisfied that local competition had taken hold.
Another key element of the act was the phase-out of price controls on cable TV, which had inhibited competition and network investment. Also mandated were telecommunications subsidies to government-run schools, health care facilities and libraries.
Unbundled Network Elements
Congress conceived of forced access to local networks as necessary to jumpstart competition in local calling services. Lawmakers assumed that new entrants would need below-cost access to the network to gain a foothold in the market. They further expected that once new entrants gained market share, they would use their new revenues to build facilities to compete against the incumbent service providers.
Lawmakers established a baseline eligibility standard for this subsidized access. Subsidized access to the incumbents’ networks was not intended to be an ongoing entitlement. Eligibility was supposed to be based on whether a competitor would be “impaired” from competing if they were denied network access.
Section 251 of the 1996 act directs the FCC to “consider, at a minimum, whether … the failure to provide access to such network elements would impair the ability of the telecommunications carrier seeking access to provide the services that it seeks to offer.”
Congress delegated to the FCC the authority to determine which switches, lines and other facilities should be shared, and how various parts of the network (called “Unbundled Network Elements,” or UNE) would be priced. The agency issued the first set of access rules in 1999. Subsequently, regulators required incumbents to provide to rivals at deeply discounted rates all elements of the network “platform” (UNE-P) as a single package. This would allow competitors simply to resell the incumbents’ services without making any investment in facilities. See Chart 7 above.
Underlying this forced-access policy is the supposition that the landline network is public property by virtue of its former monopoly status. In fact, as noted by Heritage Foundation scholars James Gattuso and Norbert Michel, today’s networks are overwhelmingly the product of investment made long after legal monopolies and guaranteed rates of return were abolished.[22] According to data from Standard & Poor’s, investors have replaced the entire capital structure of U.S. telecom companies almost twice over since passage of the Telecommunications Act of 1996.[23]
TELRIC
The FCC established a pricing formula for various network elements, such as switches and loops, called “Total Element Long-Run Incremental Cost” (TELRIC). This formula, which effectively constitutes a form of price control, is based on the estimated cost of building and operating a hypothetical maximum-efficiency network. The actual rates are set by states in accordance with the formula.
The rates calculated by most states have varied wildly and have been shown to be economically unsustainable by a variety of economists. The rate formula as applied by regulators is very subjective and rarely factors in the contributions made by network shareholders to earnings, depreciation and amortization, taxes or debt service.
Unfortunately, this regulatory approach has skewed investment incentives and undermined innovation. Most competitors have shunned investment in facilities of their own, preferring instead simply to resell the incumbents’ network services they obtain at a discount, compliments of regulatory fiat.
In Michigan, for example, most of the telephone service billed by non-incumbent competitors is actually provided by SBC facilities. According to state government data, 90 percent of the lines that non-incumbents billed to their customers in 2003 actually were serviced in whole or in part by an incumbent network, up from 62 percent in 1999.[24]
There also has been a corresponding decline in the proportion of lines served by competitors’ own facilities. In Michigan, local non-incumbents used their own facilities to service a mere 7 percent of their customers in 2003, down from 29 percent in 1999.[25]
This same dynamic is evident across the nation — an outcome that is precisely the opposite of what Congress intended.
Triennial Review Order
From a plain reading of the 1996 act, there can be no doubt that Congress intended to restrict competitors’ reliance on subsidized access to the incumbents’ networks. Yet the FCC crafted eligibility standards that effectively granted access subsidies to any and all competitors for the asking.
This disregard for congressional intent was recognized by the U.S. Supreme Court, which in 1999 struck down the first set of FCC regulations (issued three years earlier), and ordered the agency to rewrite the access rules.
A second set of standards, issued in 1999, was likewise judged to be overly broad in 2002 by the U.S. Court of Appeals for the District of Columbia. The FCC was again ordered to redraft the regulations.
The FCC issued a third set of rules, titled the “Triennial Review Order,” on Aug. 21, 2003, on a vote of 3-to-2. Commission Chairman Michael Powell, who joined Commissioner Kathleen Abernathy in dissent, publicly excoriated the majority for “taking a politically expedient course instead of the right course.”
For the first time, the rules shifted to states the responsibility for determining what market conditions would warrant subsidized access, rather than setting a federal impairment standard as Congress intended. If allowed to stand, the order would have required 50 state utility commissions to issue 50 sets of standards for determining whether competitors were eligible for subsidized network access.
To its credit, the FCC declined to require incumbents to provide subsidized access to broadband facilities, recognizing that to do so would jeopardize investment in deployment. But this recognition, while welcome, only underscored the irrationality of continuing to require forced access to the local landline network.
Once again the rules were challenged. On March 2, 2004, the U.S. Circuit Court of Appeals in Washington, D.C., ruled that the FCC had overstepped its authority. The court rejected the commission’s delegation of regulatory authority to the states, ruling that “the Commission’s position is based on a fundamental misreading of the relevant case law.” Moreover, the court ruled that the commission “made no visible effort” to determine whether forced access is, in fact, justified nationwide. On this issue, the court characterized the FCC’s findings as “vague almost to the point of being empty.”
The D.C. Circuit panel gave the FCC 60 days to rewrite the regulations, after which the forced-access rules would be vacated. A petition to extend the deadline was filed by state regulators, including the Michigan Public Service Commission, along with competing local service providers. The petition was rejected on June 14, 2004 by U.S. Supreme Court Chief Justice William Rehnquist.
On June 16, 2004, the FCC rules became legally void, creating a major opportunity for reform.
FCC Chairman Michael Powell expressed optimism that new rules could be drafted “expeditiously.” But Michigan Rep. John Dingell, noting the FCC’s history of “bizarre interpretations” of the 1996 Telecommunications Act, urged the industry to proceed freely.
“The time for legalistic bickering and squabbling has passed,” Rep. Dingell said. “All companies in the telecommunications industry should now compete vigorously, offer the new services and products that consumers want, and build the broadband infrastructure that can reinvigorate job creation.”
Access Charges
Access charges refer to payments made by long-distance carriers to local service providers for originating and terminating calls on local telephone networks. The regulation of access charge rates is therefore a form of price control.
Prior to the breakup of AT&T, regulators established artificially high long-distance rates to subsidize artificially low local service rates. To maintain local calling subsidies after the divestiture of the Bell monopoly, the FCC crafted access charges.
In most instances, a long-distance call originates on the local network, is routed to the long-distance carrier’s network and then terminates on another local network. Long-distance companies pay “access charges” to the local phone companies for carrying their calls on the local networks. The regulated access charges that long-distance companies pay range from less than one cent per minute with the former Bell companies to about 10 cents per minute with smaller, independent telephone companies.
(“Reciprocal compensation,” another type of interconnection pricing, is paid by one local phone carrier to another local carrier to terminate a local call on the latter’s network.)
Interstate access charges are regulated at the federal level, while intrastate charges are regulated by the states. This jurisdictional division is increasingly difficult to maintain as new technologies cross federal/state boundaries. For example, it remains unresolved whether Internet-based calls should incur access charges if terminated on the local network. It was precisely the high cost of access charges that helped prompt the deployment of competitive networks like Voice Over Internet Protocol (VOIP).
Because the distinction between local and long-distance calls is increasingly irrelevant, the FCC has proposed establishing one set of rules for both types of calls, a system known as “bill-and-keep.” Under bill-and-keep, carriers charge their own customers instead of other carriers for originating or terminating calls.
Universal Service
“Universal service” policies are intended to make telephone service available to all households at uniformly low rates. Thus, higher rates are applied across the board to cover the added costs of providing telephone service to rural areas, as well as to provide discounted services to low-income households. While the goal of universal service is well-intentioned, the system of fees and subsidies is threatening to collapse.
The FCC first formalized a universal service policy in the 1950s. This became the “Ozark Plan,” under which prices for long-distance telephone service were inflated to subsidize artificially low prices for local phone service. States had their own systems of “rate averaging,” some of which predate the federal system.
Today, there exist two methods of financing universal service. There are implicit charges — that is, hidden charges — built into regulated rates. This cost-shifting is a legacy of the Ozark Plan and primarily persists at the state level.
At the federal level, the Telecommunications Act of 1996 restructured universal service subsidies as explicit charges levied on telecom companies’ interstate telephone revenues. This funding stream is administered by the Federal Communications Commission, with the advice of the states.
The states determine which areas carriers must serve and their eligibility for payments from the Universal Service Fund. Nationwide, in 2002 the subsidies for carriers serving high-cost (often rural) areas reached $3 billion. Additional subsidy pools exist for advanced services to schools and libraries ($1.6 to 2.2 billion per year); rural health facilities ($16.5 million); and programs targeted to low-income telephone subscribers ($673 million).[26]
The 1996 act allows states to administer “explicit” universal service funds for intrastate service, as long as the state programs do not conflict with the federal system. Most states have programs for low-income residents; roughly half impose explicit charges on ratepayers to subsidize high-cost or small local phone companies.
The move to an explicit system for universal service was largely prompted by increased competition in long-distance and business phone services. The advent of competition made it much harder for service providers to artificially inflate rates. Consequently, there was less revenue collected to subsidize universal service programs.
Congress standardized the payments in the 1996 act by effectively imposing a universal service tax on ratepayers.
Universal service as a regulatory imperative has largely been rendered obsolete by the range of affordable services spawned by competition. For example, satellites and other wireless technologies can provide service to rural areas at much less cost than the traditional wireline network.
As it is, new technologies are penetrating the nation at an accelerating rate. Whereas it took 35 years for traditional telephone service to reach one-quarter of the population, and 26 years for television, it took only 16 years for personal computers and 13 years for cell phones.[27]
Continuing to subsidize higher-cost services will only undermine technological innovation by reducing demand for alternatives. And continuing to expand the eligibility for subsidies will needlessly burden families’ budgets. Ironically, then, a policy intended to ensure affordable service is costing consumers dearly.
Spectrum Allocation
Wireless communications are increasing in all market sectors in spite of the government’s clumsy management of the broadcast spectrum. But maximizing wireless growth and innovation requires the establishment of a spectrum market.
Since the 1920s, the federal government has managed the broadcast spectrum as a scarce public resource. Spectrum licenses were awarded only sparingly by the Federal Communications Commission, which overlooked the economic benefits of more liberal allocation.
The decade-long delay in licensing spectrum for cellular telephony, for example, is estimated to have cost at least $86 billion in lost consumer welfare.[28] In 1994, the commission forecast 54 million mobile telephone subscribers by 2000, but the number actually reached 110 million by 2000.[29]
Policymakers have made only halting progress toward a spectrum market. Congress in 1993 authorized the FCC to award wireless licenses by auction. The principal benefit of spectrum auctions is not to raise yet more money for the federal government, but to more quickly put available spectrum to commercial use.
Unfortunately, the government’s seemingly insatiable appetite for funds has slowed progress in spectrum allocation. Not until last year did the FCC finally issue rules on spectrum leasing to allow a secondary market to emerge. Leasing increases efficient use of the spectrum by providing lower-cost access to unused capacity.
Government agencies enjoy preferential use of some spectrum. Much of this bounty is not used efficiently. The FAA, for example, still uses wasteful analog technology, which requires more spectrum than digital transmission. But some reform is underway. In July 2002, the Department of Commerce released a plan in concert with the FCC and the Department of Defense to make more spectrum available for wireless services. In February 2003, the Department of Commerce agreed to release some of its spectrum allocation for wireless data communications. Finally, the FCC and the Department of Commerce approved the use of ultra-wideband (UWB) technology that enables broadband connections and assists in the performance of critical safety services.
Another casualty of the government’s poor spectrum management is the inability of various public safety agencies to communicate directly with each other. Spectrum is allocated in widely dispersed “chunks” to different agencies. And because no single radio can access all the various public safety channels, agencies are unable to communicate collectively via radio.
The Michigan Telecommunications Act
Michigan’s telecommunications law was last revised in 2002, and it sunsets on Dec. 31, 2005. In many respects, state law mirrors the federal emphasis on “managing” competition in the telecommunications market. Consequently, the Michigan act prescribes access requirements, price controls and service restrictions that actually contradict the act’s stated purpose of “encourag(ing) competition to determine the availability, prices, terms, and other conditions of providing telecommunication services.”[30]
To their credit, Michigan lawmakers recognized that advances in technology and the concomitant changes in the telecom industry warranted an overhaul of state law. Whereas past regulation was structured to control monopoly service providers, burgeoning competition has rendered such regulation obsolete. But as well-intentioned as lawmakers may have been, the legislated result was not entirely successful.
As currently written, the Michigan Telecommunications Act (MTA) still empowers state regulators to micromanage many aspects of telecom services. But the public interest would be better served by allowing competitive forces to keep rates low, service quality high and the choice of products varied.
The MTA, for example, prescribes rate plans that larger telecom service providers must offer. Given the dramatic changes in technology and consumer preferences in recent years, such mandates are anachronistic, if not downright irrational. The requirements constrain telecom companies from bundling services in response to consumer demand. But consumers are best served when their preferences, not those of regulators, dictate product offerings.
The act also defies basic economic principles by requiring that telecom providers service every customer segment of the market in which they are licensed. This prohibition on niche marketing curtails competition while robbing consumers of customized calling options.
State law also prohibits incumbent local service providers from raising rates more than once annually for basic local services. This provision was intended to protect consumers from rising rates. Over the long term, however, price controls harm consumers more than they protect them by inhibiting improvements in products and services.
This is especially true in Michigan, where basic local service rates and wholesale network access rates are set artificially low by state and federal regulators. The state formula that is used to calculate the rates, called “Total Service Long Run Incremental Cost,” assumes that networks consist of the least costly, most efficient technology currently available. But this hypothetical cost model, based on a similar federal model, does not reflect the actual network configuration or operating costs. Consequently, the incumbent service providers who own the network earn less revenue with which to invest in upgrades. Nor does it help matters that the Michigan Public Service Commission routinely takes months to resolve rate disputes — an eternity compared to the pace of market swings.
Price controls actually inhibit competition by keeping rates artificially low, thereby reducing opportunities for new entrants to compete. Consumers are left with fewer choices among products and service providers.
State lawmakers have followed their federal counterparts in requiring that incumbent providers subsidize rivals by providing access to the calling network at heavily discounted wholesale rates. Under the pre-emption doctrine, these provisions are superseded by federal law, but that has not stopped state regulators from attempting an end-run around the Federal Communications Commission.
Unfortunately, recent events highlight the troubling tendency of Michigan regulators to exceed their statutory authority. Following court rejection of federal rules on network access, the Federal Communications Commission urged incumbent service providers and their rivals to negotiate voluntary commercial agreements. In a letter to telecommunications firms and trade associations, the commissioners said: “After years of litigation and uncertainty, such agreements are needed now more than ever. … The best interests of America’s telephone consumers are served by a concerted effort to reach a negotiated arrangement.”[31]
SBC and Sage Telecom Inc. were the first to successfully negotiate a voluntary agreement. But no sooner had the companies announced their success than the Michigan Public Service Commission, without notice or hearing, demanded to review the entire agreement.
The Michigan commission was one of only five state regulatory agencies nationwide to claim regulatory power over rate changes in the absence of federal rules. In fact, Commissioner Robert Nelson implicitly threatened to bar SBC from the long-distance market if the company dared to deviate from the wholesale price controls overturned by the federal court. The Michigan commission also refused to suspend other regulatory proceedings judged to be unlawful by the federal appeals court.
Federal law does require the regional Bell operating companies to file with state commissions specific contract provisions delineated in the Telecommunications Act of 1996. However, state commissions appear to have no legal authority to approve or reject contract provisions in their entirety.
SBC and Sage have appealed the Public Service Commission order. As the petition to the FCC states, “If negotiations are tainted by regulatory overhand (sic), if a private commercial agreement is subject to approval or modification by regulators, if the terms of that agreement can be picked apart … no carrier will have much of an incentive to negotiate.”[32]
The reality is that incumbent wireline companies have an incentive to serve as wholesalers of network access without government interference. As incumbents continue to lose customers to competing technologies, they must nurture new sources of revenue. Indeed, in the weeks following the overturning of the federal “forced-access” rules, several companies negotiated private contracts.
Toll calling in Michigan supposedly is unregulated. Yet the MTA forces service providers to treat all calls to adjacent exchanges as local calls, as well as to offer a discount service plan for calls to exchanges within 20 miles of a customer’s home exchange. The cost of network restructuring required to implement this provision exceeded $30 million in the SBC territory alone.
Service providers are also prohibited from withdrawing toll service to an exchange unless an alternative provider offers the very same type of service. But high access rates among some local service providers can make toll service a losing proposition. Nonetheless, a toll provider may be forced to continue offering service that falls short of actual costs by millions of dollars.
As noted earlier in “Federal Statutes and Regulations,” regulation of network access and wholesale rates has largely failed to fulfill the original goal of meaningful competition in local wireline calling. Nor is there evidence that government interference is needed to nurture competition. Indeed, in response to the application by SBC to provide long-distance services, the Michigan Public Service Commission declared last year that Southeast Michigan, the state’s most populous service region, is open to competition. The Federal Communications Commission also accepted this finding.
In announcing the state commission’s conclusion, then-Chairwoman Laura Chappelle called on telecom firms to focus on products and services rather than on politicking. “Let the carriers duke it out, rather than [the commission] micromanaging rates,” Chappelle said.
Millions of Michigan consumers do, in fact, enjoy considerable choice as a result of new technologies, not regulation. As Deutsche Bank analysts observed: “The [incumbents] are facing steep declines in total access lines, caused by a sharp contraction in both primary and secondary lines, as wireless, DSL and cable/satellite platforms continue to cannibalize fixed line connections.”[33] These technologies are the least regulated in telecom.
The number of local wire lines in Michigan, for example, fell by more than 392,000 between 1999 and 2003, despite 2 percent growth in the state’s population and increased demand for fax and Internet lines. The lack of growth in wire lines can be explained by the increase in cellular subscriptions. There were 3.5 million wireless subscribers statewide in 1999, or slightly more than half the number of wire lines. By the end of 2002, wireless subscriptions had increased to nearly 4.9 million, or two-thirds the number of wire lines.
At this rate, there will be more wireless subscribers than wire lines in Michigan by the close of 2007.
Unfortunately, some rivals prefer regulatory arbitrage to “duking it out” in the marketplace. This is made all the more possible by provisions of the MTA that invite regulatory wrangling and litigation. For example, the MTA’s overly broad limitations on commercial speech encourage competitors to file frivolous complaints to the Public Service Commission about standard advertising claims by their rivals.
There is ample evidence of widespread competition in Michigan markets, yet state regulators remain wedded to the forced-access regime. For example, although officials in most other states have responded to the recent federal appeals court ruling by suspending their proceedings on forced-access rule-making, the Michigan Public Service Commission has moved ahead. On May 10, 2004, the administrative law judge assigned by the Public Service Commission to propose new standards for network access recommended no changes to Michigan’s access requirements, which are among the most onerous and costly in the nation.
End forced access. The growth of wireless service, cable telephony and Internet communications presents a formidable competitive challenge to wireline incumbents. Taking into account these service options, there is little justification for maintaining the forced-access regime. Service providers should be allowed to negotiate network access on mutually beneficial terms.
At the very least, limits should be set on competitors’ use of forced access. Technological innovation can radically change market conditions in a short time. Competitors who take advantage of subsidized access should be required to undergo a periodic review of eligibility. Whether they make any attempt to invest in independent facilities, as Congress intended, should be taken into account.
Rate deregulation. Price controls on network access distort competition and inhibit investment. Competitive pricing would actually impose tougher price discipline on firms than rate regulation. Service providers should be allowed to negotiate wholesale access rates, move to a “bill-and-keep” system or enter into other arrangements.
Short of full-scale deregulation, access rates should be adjusted to fully and flexibly reflect the actual costs of network services. New rates must not impose the cost of subsidizing rivals on incumbent service providers, and regulators should factor in the advantages that a competitor would gain by building an independent network.
Reform universal service. To the extent lawmakers regard universal service subsidies as necessary, market-based approaches would prove less harmful. For example, auctions could be held for the right to provide a “safe harbor” for low-income customers. Means testing should be applied to customers, rather than service providers. Finally, “implicit” support should be made “explicit,” so that consumers can see the charges on their bills and hold legislators and regulators accountable.
Avoid regulation of new services. Encouraging innovation requires maintaining a regulatory “firewall” between traditional phone service and new services like Internet telephony. Absent other regulatory changes, this approach admittedly would be unfair to traditional carriers, who are taxed in ways net-based competitors are not. But the alternative is to entangle a nascent sector of the communications industry in price controls and onerous regulation. Preserving the freedom of this new sector will ultimately benefit consumers more. The best way to “level the playing field” is to reduce taxes and regulations on incumbent carriers as well.
End regulatory disparities. All providers in a competitive marketplace should be subject to the same rules and regulations. Such regulatory “parity” should be based upon reducing regulation across-the-board, rather than imposing stricter rules industry-wide. To the extent regulation is deemed essential, lawmakers and regulators should focus only on services, not on service providers.
Reduce taxes on wireless services. Over the past five years, the cost of the average wireless plan has fallen more than 30 percent. However, state and federal taxes, fees and mandates are keeping consumers’ wireless phone bills artificially high. Nationwide, the average consumer pays 14.29 percent of their cellular phone bill in taxes. Local fees and special taxes on wireless service should be eliminated.
Privatize government telecommunications services. Consistent with sound budgeting, government agencies that use the broadcast spectrum should contract with the private sector to provide communications services, enabling the agencies to take advantage of integrated digital communications without making costly infrastructure investments of their own. Municipalities and government-run institutions should be prohibited from owning and operating a telecommunications service.
Analog |
The method of transmitting voice or data as electrical signals. |
Bandwidth |
The transmission capacity of the analog or digital line. |
Baud Rate |
The speed of an analog signal. |
Bits |
The digits used by computers to represent data for transmission. |
Broadband |
Higher-speed data transmissions, typically greater than 128 kilobits per second, in which multiple signals are simultaneously sent. |
Bundling |
The packaging of various telecommunications services by a single provider, which may include local and long-distance calling, Internet connectivity and wireless. |
CLEC |
Competitive Local Exchange Carrier. A firm offering local telephone service in competition with a former Bell company or other incumbent firm. |
Coaxial Cable |
Wide bandwidth copper cable deployed by cable TV companies. |
Compression |
Maximizing the density of data transmissions to increase transmission efficiency. |
Cramming |
Adding telecom services to a consumer’s bill without authorization. |
Dialing Parity |
The ability to place calls through a competing service provider using similar dialing patterns and without dialing extra digits or an access code. |
Digital Ethernet |
Light-wave transmissions arranged in binary units. |
LANs |
Local Area Networks. A connected set of computers and related hardware within a business or campus environment. |
LATA |
Local Access and Transport areas. The geographic delineation of local calling boundaries crafted by the U.S. Justice Department as a result of the AT&T divestiture in 1984. |
MANs |
Metropolitan Area Networks. A connected set of local computer networks. |
Modulation |
The conversion of analog signals to digital signals. |
Multiplexing |
The division of digital signals into various frequencies to allow a single line to carry multiple transmissions of voice, video and data. |
Protocols |
The operating rules governing communications transmitted between computers. |
Slamming |
Changing a service provider without customer authorization. |
TELRIC | Total Element Long-Run Incremental Cost. The formula devised by the Federal Communications Commission to calculate the fees allowed for wholesale access to the local incumbent network. |
Twisted Pair | The copper wire used in the standard local telephone network. |
VOIP | Voice Over Internet Protocol. Transmission of voice calls through Internet connections. |
Federal Communications Commission |
|
Michigan Public Service commission |
|
MichiganVotes |
|
Progress and Freedom Foundation |
|
Telecommunications Association of Michigan |
|
United States Telecom Association |
United States Telecom Association, Washington, D.C., http://usta.org.
Federal Communications Commission, “Broadband Internet Access in OECD Countries: A Comparative Analysis,” Washington, D.C., October 2003.
Federal Communications Commission, “High-Speed Services for Internet Access: Status as of December 31, 2003,” June 2004.
Federal Communications Commission, “Trends in Telephone Service,” May 2004.
United States Telecom Association, “Statement on Early Success of Commercial Negotiations in the Telecom Sector,” Washington, D.C., April 5, 2004.
Thierer, A., “Unnatural Monopoly: Critical Moments in the Development of the Bell System Monopoly,” Washington, D.C., The Cato Journal, Fall 1994.
Ibid.
Telecommunications Association of Michigan, “The Michigan Telecommunications Act Handbook,” 2003 edition.
Ibid.
Ibid, quoting Michigan Public Service Commission, Citizens Telephone Co. of Grand Rapids, PUR 1921 E: 308, 315.
Thierer, A., “Unnatural Monopoly: Critical Moments in the Development of the Bell System Monopoly,” Washington, D.C., The Cato Journal, Fall 1994.
Ibid.
Crandall, Robert W., “A Somewhat Better Connection,” Regulation, Summer 2002, p. 24.
Reed, Lawrence, “Seven Principles of Sound Public Policy,” The Mackinac Center for Public Policy, Midland, MI, Oct. 2001.
Federal Communications Commission, “Statistics of the Long Distance Telecommunications Industry,” May 2003.
Cellular Telecommunications & Internet Association in Federal Communications Commission, “Trends in Telephone Service,” May 2004.
Federal Communications Commission, “Trends in Telephone Service,” May 2004.
Ibid.
Adkinson Jr., William F., Heinecke, Erik T., Lenard, Thomas M., “The Digital Economy Fact Book,” The Progress and Freedom Foundation, 2003.
Ibid.
Ibid.
Gattuso, James and Michel, Norbert, “Are U.S. Telecom Networks Public Property?,” The Heritage Foundation, Washington, D.C., April 8, 2004.
Ibid.
Michigan Public Service Commission, “Status of Telecommunications Competition in Michigan,” May 2004.
Ibid.
Federal and State Staff for the Federal-State Joint Board on Universal Service in CC Docket No. 96-45, Universal Service Monitoring Report CC Docket No. 98-202, 2003.
Cox, W. Michael, and Alm, R., “The Economy at Light Speed: Technology and Growth in the Information Age and Beyond,” 1996, p. 10.
Crandall, R.W., and Sidak, J.G., “Competition and Regulatory Policies for Interactive Broadband Networks,” California Law Review, 1995.
Federal Communications Commission, “Annual Report and Analysis of Competitive Market Conditions With Respect to Commercial Mobile Services,” Washington, D.C., 2001.
Michigan Telecommunications Act, Article 1, Sec. 101(1b).
Press Statement of Chairman Michael K. Powell and Commissioners Kathleen Q. Abernathy, Michael J. Copps, Kevin J. Martin and Jonathan S. Adelstein On Triennial Review Next Steps, March 31, 2004.
SBC Communications Inc., “Emergency Petition for Declaratory Ruling, Preemption and for Standstill Order to Preserve the Viability of Commercial Negotiations,” May 3, 2004.
Deutsche Bank, 2Q03 Review, Sept. 2003.
Diane Katz is director of science, environment and technology policy for the Mackinac Center for Public Policy. Her recent Mackinac Center studies include analyses of Michigan's telecommunications market, environmental cleanup and land preservation programs. Before joining the Mackinac Center in 2001, Ms. Katz spent 17 years with The Detroit News — eight years as a reporter, and nine years as a member of the editorial board specializing in science and the environment, telecommunications and technology, and the auto industry. Her work has won numerous journalism awards and has been published by The Wall Street Journal, The Washington Times and National Review.
The author wishes to thank Solveig Singleton, formerly of the Competitive Enterprise Institute (CEI), for assisting with the sections on access charges and universal service. Braden Cox, technology counsel with CEI's Project on Technology and Innovation, also provided valuable help on the issue of spectrum allocation.